Argentina’s Industrial History Shows the Follies of Raúl Prebisch’s Developmentalism
One of the big
international news stories of August 2023 was that a country usually seen as
not particularly noteworthy on the global stage, Argentina, might be the first
in the world to have a self-described libertarian President in the form of
Javier Milei. He received a slight plurality of over 30% of the vote in a
presidential primary that plays a key indicator of who is likely to win the
election in October. Beyond just simple surprise at the fact that a libertarian
who was not Ron Paul was getting attention, as well as the natural journalistic
temptation to make a dubious comparison between Milei and Donald Trump and Jair
Bolsonaro, many were even more shocked by the results because of the long
history of heavy government intervention in the Argentine economy and the rapid
change in policy that the winning candidate was proposing, particularly in
regards to trade.
Really
since the start of the Great Depression, but particularly since the election of
Juan Domingo Perón in 1946,
Argentina has, with the exception of the 1976-1983 military junta and the
presidency of Carlos Menem from 1989 to 1999, almost always been an extremely
protectionist country, bordering on autarchic in some time periods. As of 2023,
the average tariff rate is 11.9%, compared to 2.3% for the United States.
Milei’s pledge to throw open the country to free trade is thus a particularly
welcoming proposition for a country where 40% of the population is in poverty
and an 11.9% charge for foreign products cannot be doing anything to help with
that. All that being said, the question that naturally comes to mind is why did
a country that was once a major exporter of agricultural products suddenly turn
to extreme protectionism, even long after the worldwide anti-trade streak
during the Great Depression had passed. For that, we have to look to the
so-called developmentalist theories of an Argentine economist named Raúl Prebisch.
Prebisch, who had once
subscribed to the principle of free trade, decided to turn his back on the
policy when he noticed the effects of the Great Depression on his native
Argentina. From 1880 to 1930, Argentina’s economy was primarily a rapidly
expanding agricultural exporter that specialized in cattle, wheat, flaxseed,
corn, and other staple crops. This made the country very rich, with real wages
amounting to about 96% of the United Kingdom’s by the early 20th
century and a much better standard of living to be found among the millions of
immigrants, primarily from Italy and Spain, that the country received. The
Great Depression, unfortunately, but perhaps understandably, changed that
perception and ideas of changing the agro-export model took hold. This was the
environment where the theories of Prebisch could take hold. According to him,
the problem facing Argentina and much of the rest of the raw materials-exporting
developing world were that they were in the “Periphery” and would be doomed to
keep exporting raw materials in perpetuity and would never develop on their
own. The solution, therefore, was for these countries to throw up massive trade
barriers and industrialize for an internal market in order to avoid downturns
like the one they were in in the 1930s and only then would they become wealthy.
There are multiple problems with this theory, but sticking with Argentina in
particular, the largest one would be the fact that Argentina was not only an
agricultural exporter at this time and was indeed already fairly industrialized
at the time of Prebisch’s writing and as a result, the subsequent obsession
with industrialization for the sake of self-sufficiency that occurred under
Juan Perón and whose legacy continues on today with Argentina’s relatively
large amount of protectionism the country suffers under has quite possibly been
largely redundant.
While it is necessary
to be fair and not try to paint Argentina as some kind of free trade paradise
prior to the start of the import industrialization substitution that the
country pursued after the Great Depression, it should be noted that most of the
tariffs imposed at that time were largely for revenue-generating purposes. It
was only the odd politically-connected industry, such as wine from Mendoza or
sugar from Tucuman, that received explicitly protectionist favoritism. With
that out of the way, the history of Argentine industry that developed with no
help from the state (and that Prebisch would have been wise to read about)
deserves to be recounted. As Mauricio Rojas recounts in The Sorrows of Carmencita, between 1900 and 1913, industry had
multiplied by 2.4 times and the 633,000 people employed in industry in the 1910-1914
period accounted for 20.6% of the Argentine workforce. They were spread out
across over 48,000 workplaces. This hardly sounds like the feudal backwater
dominated by landed oligarchs that Peronist propaganda famously claimed to be
taking on. Whatever else this indicates, it is that autarky is not necessary to
develop a country. Even Henry Clay in America never went that far.
So, what does the historic
trade policy of Argentina have to do with modern politics in the nation. Well, for
one thing, it illustrates just one of the many ways that Javier Milei wants to
pull the country out of the policy decisions that should have been left in the
1970s and brought into the modern world economy to become the developed country
that Argentina has long been seen as destined to be. Adopting a liberal trade
policy akin to next-door Chile and Uruguay’s would likely be an easy place to
start. After all, who does not like cheaper products, regardless of where they
were produced. Even if Milei does not win in October, hopefully his trade
recommendations will be taken to heart.
Comments
Post a Comment