Johan Norberg Surprisingly Endorsed Land Reform as a Prerequisite for Prosperity
Johan
Norberg is perhaps the classical liberal historian most famous for rebutting
the fallacious claims about the supposed socialism of the Scandinavian
countries around 2015 when such rumors were being spread by Bernie Sanders’ presidential
campaign and before that, as the economist who best broke down why Naomi Klein’s
The Shock Doctrine was a very flawed
book, built much more on ideology than sound history or political economy. It
was, however, with his 2001 book In Defense
of Global Capitalism, that he really cut his teeth and it is because of that
book that he seems to be much more qualified than most Reason or Cato Institute
scholars to talk about issues in a way that can only be described as less
ideological. The example of this? The issue of land reform and how it could
have stopped economic populist madmen, like Juan Peron in Argentina or Getulio Vargas
in Brazil, from rising to power. This must have been especially brazen given
the climate that this was happening right before the book was published. In
2000, the Marxist-inspired Robert Mugabe had just started seizing farms without
expropriation and was beginning what would be a very long and painful downfall of
Zimbabwe, and in particular, their former role as the breadbasket of southern
Africa. So how could one defend land reform when such events were transpiring
and why was Latin America in the 20th century in need of it in order
to develop a successful economic base that wouldn’t fall prey to strongmen
savior-type politicians? Well, the answer there is the same as in all other
former colonial countries: the state-backed parceling out of land that happened
under the old colonial powers was an injustice that could be corrected on
libertarian grounds, as well as the need to have a nation predominantly of individual
capitalist farmers, rather than tenants living in a bizarre mix of capitalism
and feudalism, in order to have a culture of prosperity and stability.
So,
what of this first claim? Surely, not all of the Americas were individually
dished out to cronies by former colonial rulers and their descendants were just
able to live the easy life as rent-collectors, while everyone else was in
perpetual bondage as serfs, right? Well, that was thankfully not the case in
places like the United States, Canada, and Australia, but when it came to Latin
America, that unfortunately was much of what happened. Argentina would probably
be the country most famous for this. They are said to have been totally at the
mercy of a landed oligarchy and it was only by Juan Peron’s coming to power
that they were brought to heel. This vastly oversimplifies the Argentine land
question and even the fact that many immigrants obtained land, but in his 1980
book, The Epic of Latin America, biographer
John A. Crow relates the anecdote of a member of the Argentine Congress saying
that less than 2,000 people owned more land in the country than what existed in
all of Italy, Belgium, Holland, and Denmark combined. Whatever truth this
statistic holds is beyond the point. Argentina may be a huge country, but this
land concentration created economic problems of its own, as land became a form
of status and living off of rents was seen by the elite to be superior to
industry and commerce. Unsurprisingly, it was thus mostly only the immigrant
communities in pre-Peronist Buenos Aires who got the country’s non-agricultural
sector off the ground. Almost everything else was British foreign investment.
The average Joe tenant farmer in the Pampas was not going to be granted title
to the land that he worked and thus his Argentina was not going to be able to
be a nation of capitalist agriculturalists, like New Zealand, Canada, or
Norberg’s own Sweden have been and still are to one extent or another, but rather
a backwards rentier economy more akin to a banana republic for cattle and wheat
that exists due to the force of a former colonial government, rather than any
Lockean homesteading. This problem could then be extrapolated to pretty much
all of Latin America and one of the regions’ big problem with economic
development comes to the fore. It is with this background that Norberg risks
perpetual reminders of the existence of Zimbabwe and accusations of not being a
real libertarian, where he proposes the unthinkable: that the formerly feudal
land grants be broken up and the farmers on this land gain titleship.
Fittingly
grounding himself in classical liberal theory, he uses the examples of Latin
American countries not just to promote land reform, but at the same time, to
denounce the Marxist-inspired dependency theory that did take hold in the
country. After writing: that “Land reforms to put an end to centuries of
feudalism would have been needed, coupled with a commitment to education and
free markets”, he points out how instead of seeing land concentration as the
problem, academics responded to the decreased trade from the Great Depression
by embracing import-substitution industrialization and turning their backs on
trade. All of this greatly contributed to Latin America’s economic backwardness.
Putting Latin America aside, it is interesting that a classical liberal could
in this day and age call for land reform. Ever since Murray Rothbard rejected
the land value tax, it has seemed to be unspeakable to point out the pre-capitalist
conditions for much of land ownership in the world today. The current land distribution
is seldom considered a problem, regardless of how feudal its roots go. Norberg
did not go this far, but it seems taxing away the annual rental value of land
is the most realistic and peaceful way to create a nation of farmer entrepreneurs
in a formally feudal country. That is, after all, close to how the birthplace
of Norberg’s icon, Anders Chyndenius, started down the track to being the modern
capitalist nation of Finland that they are today. In order to stop Soviet-influence
in the country, feudal tenancy was largely put to an end by the 1930s and the Finns
who had once embraced the Bolsheviks were ready to beat back the Red Army in
the Winter War. Perhaps with a similar reform in Argentina, the tyranny of Juan
Peron and his toxic Kirchnerist legacy would not haunt the country to this day.
Comments
Post a Comment